A concise analysis of competition law developments in Japan
Author: Akihiko Nakagawa
The Japanese Supreme Court ruled that blanket licensing of broadcasting rights by the dominant copyright collection society (JASRAC) would constitute an exclusionary conduct, when per work royalties are extraordinary high as a reasonable alternative to a blanket licensing.
The Supreme Court seems to think that the blanket licensing in this case satisfies the artificiality prong, because consumers (broadcasters) are denied the choice of per-work licensing. In other words, if the instant licensing is a normal method of competition, JASRAC should offer more patterns of licensing for consumers. Such reasoning, which starts from a desirable outcome of competition rather than from a counterfactual, could be overreaching: Any profit maximizing conduct by a dominant firm could satisfy artificiality.
The Supreme Court's artificiality prong goes back to the NTT East case: a price-squeeze case handed down in 2010. The court based their interpretation of exclusionary conducts on Art.1. Art. 1 of the Antimonopoly Act describes the purpose of the Act. Reliance on statutory text is a traditional way of interpretation for lawyers, but potentially puzzling for economists who focus on underlying facts and predicted equilibriums.
The Japanese system of reviewing JFTC's decisions has been changed by the 2013 amendment. The trial proceeding in JFTC tribunal will be replaced by that in Tokyo district court. The Supreme Court seems to be in haste to announce a guidepost on exclusionary conducts for the lower courts, though the JASRAC case will not be affected by the amendment.
Japanese competition authority (Japanese Fair Trade Commission; JFTC) reduced its fine imposed on Toys"R"Us from about 369 million yen to 222 million yen, around a 40 percent reduction. Toys"R"Us decided NOT to appeal this decision to the Tokyo High Court.